An upscale restaurant in Karachi | Arif Mahmood, White Star **In the past few months,** activists associated with a farm tenants’ group, Anjuman Muzaraeen Punjab (AMP), have blocked the National Highway near Okara and Sahiwal several times. The reason for their agitation is a long-standing feud with the military, over rights of ownership of land which these farmers have cultivated for many decades. They are also angry over the continuous harassment of the group’s leaders by the police. So far their movement has only resulted in a precarious détente which is often interrupted by the state’s heavy handedness.
AMP is one of the few organisations working actively for farm labourers and tenants. The rest of the associational landscape in rural Pakistan consists of organisations representing large scale and mid-sized landowners (such as Pakistan Kissan Ittehad and abadkar boards) that lobby the government for agricultural support prices and other subsidies. For the last many months, these organisations have been agitating that the government should provide a cushion to the agriculture sector against the adverse impacts of falling prices in global commodity markets. In September 2015, after several rounds of protests, the government gave in and announced a multi-billion rupee farm support package to help shore up profits for landowners and cultivators.
The announcement of the package shows who has power and influence in the rural areas, those with political and economic resources. Those on the margins, such as farm labourers, are rarely, if ever, heard in the corridors of power. Naturally, the political calculus drives the government to provide subsidies to landowners. Nothing is more symptomatic of this calculus than the continuing use of a leakage-prone support price mechanism for wheat. If nothing else, this mechanism overwhelmingly favours farmers and landowners with connections to the food department and other procurement agencies.
Meant to boost rural incomes by setting a minimum price above the one prevailing in the free market, support price mechanism is flawed for several important reasons. Firstly, even in areas classified as rural, the majority of the population is now a net consumer of wheat, rather than a net producer (only 37 per cent of all rural households own some amount of land). Secondly, the state’s procurement centres cover a vast area, thus creating room for selective provision of procurement logistics to those farmers and landowners who have the political and monetary resources to avail those logistics. Thirdly, the absence of universal outreach of procurement centres and lack of storage facilities means that many small and uninfluential farmers, will be left at the mercy of a grain market controlled by extortionist middlemen.
With landownership and incidence of poverty showing some correlation, rural inequality rates remain staggeringly high. By 2008, slightly less than a third of all rural residents (30 per cent) were living in chronic poverty. On the other hand, two per cent people in the villages owned about 30 per cent of all cultivable land.
There is a strong correlation between lengthened access to land (provided by fixed tenancy contracts) and socio-economic well-being measured through long-term health and education outcomes.
Tenancy contracts which offer livelihood security to those with small or no landholdings are on the decline. As inter-generational landholdings become smaller, and farming becomes market-driven, landowners prefer to utilise wage labourers over long-term tenants or, at least, give out land on sharecropping contracts. Tractor subsidies given by the government, which reduce the need for farm labourers, favour landowners and have resulted in a 37 per cent decline in tenancy contracts over the past four decades. The state, in essence, has forced peasants to become unemployed rural labourers through its own policies. Nearly 44 per cent of the rural population is now engaged in informal wage labour of some kind.
According to research by Ali Cheema, Farooq Naseer and others, there is a strong correlation between lengthened access to land (provided by fixed tenancy contracts) and socio-economic well-being measured through long-term health and education outcomes. Families forced off land, or turned into net-sellers of labour on a seasonal basis, have access to fewer resources to invest in improving their human capital. This results in long-term poverty traps, successive generations will fail to improve their standard of living because they are too poor to invest into learning skills that earn high wages.
During the 1960s and early 1970s, tenant associations had managed to secure some important concessions from the state. This happened mainly because of political activism in rural areas: by left-wing parties such as Mazdoor Kissan Party as well as by PPP’s kissan and hari committees. These organisations focused specifically on ensuring occupancy rights for tenant farmers which helped in the long-term alleviation of rural poverty. The driving philosophy behind this was simple: contrary to neoclassical economic assumptions, excess farm labour will not be fully absorbed by a growing urban economy; in the long run, urban growth will happen in less labour-absorbing sectors (as is currently happening in Pakistan) and, thus, it was thought important to secure the livelihood of non-landowners in the rural economy.
One of the biggest concessions gained by the peasant mobilisations was improved tenancy protection laws promulgated by the Bhutto government. This law allowed tenants legal protection from forced eviction and gave them the right of first purchase, in case the landowner decided to sell the land. Another major concession obtained was homestead rights on rural land which allowed the rural underclass access to residential land in their villages.
However, these victories have proven short-lived. As soon as tenant protection became enshrined in law, landowners figured out informal mechanisms to avoid its implementation. Utilising their political and social networks, they managed to bribe or coerce district administrations into allowing forceful evictions. This has resulted in a situation where, regardless of the protection accorded by law, rural landlessness and the number of rural labourers continue to increase.
On a recent day off from work, Zahid walks over to a tea shop near his place of residence. The television in one corner of the shop is showing news related to the upcoming by-election in a Lahore constituency. One of his co-workers lives in that constituency and has been talking about how the assistant to the PTI candidate has promised a new sanitation scheme for his neighbourhood. Apparently, the candidate has made the same promise at several other locations. Half-jokingly, Zahid thinks out aloud that it will be a good thing if the member of the National Assembly in his home constituency is disqualified, too. A by-election is probably the only way he might get a new sewerage line for his street.
When asked if he has ever thought of becoming a part of some collective action for better living conditions, Zahid says no. There is little chance that such an action will work, he suggests. It just seems common sense to him to keep his head down and go about his life without asking for anything.
In Pakistan the prospects of a new social contract, one in which the poor have an equal right to public resources and the state serves the need of the many, as opposed to the few, are minimal.
There is no way for him to know what collective action has achieved in human history. The creation of the welfare state in Europe after it was destroyed during World War II was made possible mainly through the decade-long struggle of politically organised and mobilised sections of the working class. The welfare state guaranteed universal access to health care, massive improvements in public education, access to affordable housing, social security and pensions and, most importantly, dignified employment that offered secure opportunities for upward mobility.
Today the welfare state exists only precariously in many parts of the world in the face of an aggressive introduction of neo-liberal economic policies, which emphasise on rolling back the role of the state from most fields of life. Yet its importance and role in overcoming the social and economic impacts of war, poverty and strife cannot be understated. In Pakistan, however, the prospects of a new social contract, one in which the poor have an equal right to public resources and the state serves the need of the many, as opposed to the few, are minimal.
The country may recover from terrorism, soon. What, however, seems less likely is that the plight of the poor will change for the better in the foreseeable future. Given the indifference and arrogance of those with power and resources, huge segments of the society appear condemned to live economically bleak lives day in and day out — with no end in sight.
This was originally published in Herald's October 2015 issue. To read more, subscribe to Herald's print edition.