Photo courtesy: dawn.com
Moral of the story first: prolonged interaction breeds complacency and self-interest.
The latest International Monetary Fund (IMF) loan programme for Pakistan concluded in September 2016. It was deemed a success: the country’s economy is doing reasonably well after three years under it.
The state of the economy, however, may not have much to do with the programme. There is, in fact, a strong expectation that Pakistan may again seek help from the IMF if its finances become insufficient to meet its external trade and debt repayment needs.
Our relationship with the Fund (that is, dependency) can be better understood by looking at our past. The IMF is generally approached for help when a country faces a balance of payments problem. Although this remains the main reason for Pakistan requesting money from the Fund, the IMF programmes in Pakistan (and in other countries) since the 1990s have focused more on introducing comprehensive changes in the structure of the economy than just providing support for hard currency needs.
There is, in fact, a strong expectation that Pakistan may again seekhelp from the IMF if its finances become insufficient.
Since December 1988, Pakistan has had nine separate engagements with the IMF — three of them were double programmes. That means there have been 12 IMF programmes in Pakistan in the last 28 years. Only four of them – all initiated in the 2000s and 2010s – were completed successfully; all the rest were abandoned halfway in the 1990s.
The turning point came in 2000 when Pakistan was facing the possibility of defaulting on its foreign debts by the end of the year. One should recall that Pakistan had fallen out of favour with the West in May 1998 (when it conducted nuclear tests) and subsequently in 1999 (due to Pervez Musharraf’s military coup). Seeking help from the IMF was the only option available to Islamabad in those circumstances.
This constraint put the government in a situation where it had to accept and abide by the terms and conditions attached to the loan agreement with the IMF (signed in November 2000 and completed in September 2001).
Also read: Is Pakistan heading towards a serious debt problem?
A close look at the three remaining completed programmes reveals that two of them were clearly linked to positive external developments (positive shocks). The three-year programme that started in December 2001, for instance, was supported by debt rescheduling/write-offs and generous grants by the United States after 9/11; the three-year Extended Fund Facility programme initiated in November 2013 became irrelevant after the collapse of world oil prices in mid-2014.
The successful completion of an IMF programme, thus, clearly depends on political will within the government, as well as helpful external developments. This raises a question: what exactly does the IMF do to ensure the success of its programmes?
Doctor-patient parable
By the IMF’s own acknowledgement in 2002, Pakistan was third in a list of 51 countries described as “prolonged users” of its financial support. Our peers were the Philippines (#1), Panama (#2), Kenya (#7) and Argentina (#16). Pakistan continues to rank high on that list.
A parable may help illustrate Pakistan’s complicated relationship with the IMF.
The incentive for a doctor (IMF in this case) to maintain a relationship with a patient (the country receiving an IMF loan) is pretty straightforward. If the patient fully recovers, the doctor may feel professionally satisfied but he will also lose a customer.
The IMF was created as a lender of last resort for governments thatcannot get a loan from any other source.
A ‘well-intentioned’ doctor will prescribe bitter medicine and demand behavioural changes – he will not allow the patient an easy way out – irrespective of the fact that this will lose him a client. A ‘self-serving’ doctor, on the other hand, will yield to the patient’s reluctance to change bad habits and prescribe milder medication; the doctor will also schedule regular visits to keep administering the palliative.
But after remaining bedridden for almost a decade, why doesn’t the patient (Pakistan) insist on a course of treatment that actually cures him? In our view, this is because the patient is under the charge of his aunt (the government). As with the doctor, we also assume the aunt is either well-intentioned (she wants the patient to recover) or self-serving (she wants to keep the patient weak so that she can continue living in his house).
Any doctor should be able to see through the motivation of the aunt. But it is not that simple — the doctor reports to a board which insists that the aunt has the final say (as the guardian of the patient). The issue is this: why does the doctor continue to treat the patient after eight failed treatments that have focused on the same illness? Why does the doctor not adopt a tough-love approach? Why does the aunt not demand a more effective treatment that will show results?
Game theory